RPI vs CPI: the row goes on
Two new contributions to the argument over how the UK measures inflation show that the issue is far from dead. Arcane the argument may be, but its effects are not.
The decision by the Coalition Government in June 2010 to change the way benefits and public sector pensions are uprated from the Retail Price Index (RPI) to the Consumer Price Index (CPI) means that millions are affected – and, in general, disadvantaged – by a change that has also left many statisticians uneasy.
A excellent summary of the issue, written by Jill Leyland for the Royal Statistical Society, is available on the Significance website. The nub of the issue is that inflation measured by CPI is generally lower than that measured by RPI and over the years, it adds up. Since 1996, when CPI was introduced, its measure of cumulative inflation is 35.6 per cent, while RPI has it at 53.6 per cent. A pensioner who retired that year and whose pension was uplifted by RPI would now be 13 per cent better off than one whose pension was uplifted by CPI.
Some of this difference, which has averaged 0.88 percentage points a year, is due to what is included in the basket of goods and services whose prices are recorded as the first step in constructing the index. But a substantial part of the difference, an average of 0.53 percentage points a year, has been the result of the so-called “formula effect” – the way in which changes in prices are aggregated into an index.
This gap, says Dr Mark Courtney in a critique published this month on the Social Science Research Network, is “embarrassingly large for a mere difference in statistical technique, and much larger than in other countries”. In 2010 it widened to an average of 0.81 percentage points, which the Office for National Statistics attributed to changes in the way it collected prices for clothing and footwear.
In constructing both indices, the first stage involves working out the price growth (or decline) for each of the 680-odd items included in the basket. The RPI does this by averaging the changes between the present period and the previous one for each set of prices collected by its monitors, using the arithmetic mean. The CPI, in contrast, calculates from much the same data the geometric mean of the price changes. (For n items, the arithmetic mean is the sum of the values divided by n; the geometric mean results from multiplying all values together and taking the nth root.)
It can be shown mathematically that the wider the range of price changes for any item in any period, the greater the difference between the geometric and arithmetic means. The widening gap between CPI and RPI is the result, says the ONS, of changes to the way it measured prices – allowing sales goods to be included in the base period, for example, or including all items in the base period even if they were likely to go out of stock. That increased the dispersion of price changes, and hence the gap between CPI and RPI.
But Dr Courtney argues that, while true, this misses the real issue, which is what determines these prices in the first place. The indices assume that price increases are the result of changes on the supply side: higher wages for workers producing the goods, higher raw material prices, higher energy or transport costs, etc. They ignore changes on the demand side, such as changes in fashion that may drive down the price of last year’s clothes and enable retailers to charge a premium on this year’s more fashionable items. Such changes, he argues, lead to underestimates of the inflation rate because the ways the index is constructed gives greater weight to price falls than to price rises.
The second problem he identifies is that the UK uses price data originally devised for the RPI to construct the CPI. Other countries have much more tightly defined categories of items for which prices are collected: either more homogenous categories, or those that have high levels of substitutability. This makes them appropriate for an index constructed using the geometric mean, which assumes that consumers will switch from one product to another when prices change.
But RPI was designed differently, with looser categories and a different method of averaging which were not ideal for the CPI. This didn’t matter much while the CPI were simply used as a harmonised measure of inflation within the EU, its original purpose. The CPI may have underestimated UK inflation, but it did so in a consistent way, so could be used to set a target, so long as that target was lower than it was for RPI (a fact recognised by lowering the target from 2.5 per cent to 2.0 per cent). But when CPI was adopted for benefit and pension uprating, its defects as an inflation measure become very important indeed.
A second attack on CPI has come from Dr Gareth Jones, in a letter to Sir Michael Scholar, chair of the UK Statistics Authority. He argues that the use of the geometric mean does not represent how consumers actually behave. What the geometric mean actually assumes is that brands that gain sales will be those whose percentage increases in price are below average, regardless of their actual price, he maintains. And that is implausible.
Suppose we have two brands priced initially at £1 and 50p. If the more expensive brand increases in price by 2 per cent and the cheaper brand by 10 per cent, their prices will be £1.02 and 55p respectively. Will consumers switch to the more expensive brand because the differential in price has fallen from 50p to 47p? He argues they won’t.
But replying on behalf of Sir Michael, National Statistician Jil Matheson says yes they will, because of the greater utility or product satisfaction provided by the more expensive product. She cites a rival case of two brands costing 60p and 50p. One increases by 5 per cent to 63p, the other by 20 per cent to 60p. The price differential has fallen from 10p to 3p, and consumers will switch to the dearer brand because they now perceive it to be better value.
The difference between these two examples, of course, is homogeneity. Dr Jones has chosen brands that differ greatly in price, Dr Matheson brands whose prices are close. Both make a plausible case, based on their premises.
But which represents reality better? In the clothing market, where price differentials are large and where the ONS tripped up, one might feel that Dr Jones’ example is closer to real life. That brings us back to Dr Courtney’s call for more tightly-drawn and homogenous item categories to lower the dispersion of relative price changes, and the use where appropriate of a different averaging method in the first stage of calculation. .
The RSS has called for a re-examination of this stage, using retailers’ knowledge of how consumers behave, coupled with appropriate data collection, and the ONS has undertaken to examine the issue. But what the RSS seeks is a better version of the RPI, with the CPI reverting to its old name, the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices, so as to remove confusion over what it actually measures.
Would these changes, desirable as they are, induce the Government to revert to RPI for uprating pensions and benefits? Given that it would cost more, that seems very unlikely. The public will continue to pay for the confusion that enabled a cash-strapped government to take cover behind an index that is not fit for purpose.
Update, August 25:
Dr Jones himself is unconvinced by Jil Matheson’s reply. He says that in her example you could replace 60p by £60 and the degree of substitution would be unchanged. Claims that the notion that price levels of different brands do not affect substitution behaviour is “really beyond reasonable belief”, he says, consumers often being unaware of recent prices changes, and basing their decisions on price levels.
Countries that have used the geometric mean (GM) in their price indices have made “a serious error” to which users of ONS data, including the media, should be alerted. He adds that there are 9 EU countries, including Germany, that do not use it. “It is therefore quite wrong to say that the UK is in any way following an international consensus”.
Dr Jones has put these views in a response to UKSA, which will no doubt appear on UKSA’s website soon.
Jill Leyland (not verified) wrote,
Wed, 24/08/2011 - 11:13
Thanks Nigel for an excellent summary of this issue. But perhaps I could clarify one small point in your penultimate paragraph where you say that "what the RSS seeks is a better version of the RPI". What we are asking for is an index, or family of indices, that reflect household spending and are appropriate for "compensation" purposes eg uplift of pensions, salary reviews etc. We are, at the moment, agnostic as to whether this would be a better version of the RPI, or a better version of the CPI, a mixture of the two or something else entirely. The decision should be based on user needs and on a full examination of the formula effect issue. We understand that the ONS is now undertaking the latter and the RSS and ONS are working together to set up a user group. Hope this makes sense!
Nigel Hawkes (not verified) wrote,
Wed, 24/08/2011 - 14:21
Thanks, Jill, perfectly clear. I've also updated by adding a link to Mark Courtney's abstract - from which the whole article can be downloaded if you register. For some reason the link didn't appear first time round
David Quinn (not verified) wrote,
Wed, 24/08/2011 - 19:29
I am just a punter, not a statistician, but I found this article both interesting and illuminating as to the ebb and flow of the argument. I am interested partly because my private sector pension has gone to CPI and partly because I believe, as the article pretty well says, the government is using a confidence trick to progressively steal enormous sums from most of the population (actually all of it if you consider the adoption of CPI for tax allowance uprating).
The point I want to make is that the examples given here on both sides miss the point somewhat because they are not based on practicality. The RSS in a letter to UKSA has said that CPI is not an accurate measure because people are reluctant to substitute. I would go further. I believe that pricing is pretty artificial in our brand-ridden and supermarket- controlled economy. Prices are set by supermarkets in a sophisticated way which is not wholly to do with quality but is related to it. They would tend to charge more for their branded goods than their “own-brand” goods and would charge more for premium own- brands than their standard own-brands. In this world a shift by consumers from brands and premium own-brands would tend to incur a loss in quality. That is supermarkets’ intention. It may be that shifting from a branded or premium own-brand item to a standard own-brand item would not incur a loss in quality but it would be pretty difficult to predict this reliably. It would take quite a bit of trial and error and of course the sourcing of all these items and therefore their quality is constantly changing so the consumer would always be behind this game. For some items consumers may have long established their choice. So I would buy Heinz baked beans rather than supermarkets’ own but would never think of buying other than Sainsbury’s, for example, kidney beans or frozen broad beans. But such choices were made some time ago and are not available for further substitution. The government and ONS might argue that an alternative would be to buy at cheaper supermarkets, specifically the discounters such as Lidl and Aldi. There are two objections to this. Although some items are probably of equal or better quality in the discounters choosing these reliably is nearly a fantasy and the discounters supply chain is even more volatile than the major supermarkets. Secondly supermarkets are often a local monopoly and there are relatively few Lidls and Aldis.
To sum up therefore I feel that the stickiness of substitution is more structural than just reluctance on consumers’ part. So the theoretical examples above just don’t matter. Substitution with preserved satisfaction is a near impossibility in today’s world. The concept smacks to me of economists rather than statisticians. It is some Chicago Schooler’s wet dream. It reminds me of the now-discredited Absolute Income Hypothesis (as opposed to the Relative Income Hypothesis) beloved of monetarists. They needed the AIH to prove that a more unequal society floated all boats. Like this the substitution/preserved satisfaction idea is a Convenient Untruth, to paraphrase Al Gore, which government has seized on to commit daylight robbery.
Of course most of the population have no notion of what is going on and cannot defend themselves. In this environment I believe it behoves the RSS to stop being so mealy mouthed in their criticism and come out strongly and vociferously against CPI. I was somewhat cheered by the news in your article that a working party is being set up to adopt a more accurate measure. I only hope this does its work in my lifetime. We have a short breathing period, but once interest rates rise we could see the indices springing apart by 3 or 4 % because of the effect on mortgages. This might not affect so many existing pensioners but would certainly greatly diminish the value of the future pensions of those in work with a CPI based pension, i.e. all of the public sector and half of the private sector, as well as all taxpayers and state benefit recipients. Please RSS. Make a bigger fuss.
Graham Cole (not verified) wrote,
Thu, 25/08/2011 - 20:49
An excellent summary. So, where do we go from here ?
It's obvious that all in the government know CPI is an unfit measure for inflation. It is merely a convenient way to reduce pensions and hence the deficit.
However, even more annoying is the BT approach which didn't make a jot of difference to our country's debt. Here, with suspicious haste, CEO Ian Livingstone siezed upon the opportunity to rob BT pensioners, future and present by immediately slashing £2.8 Billion off BT's pension fund debt. so improving the company's, not the country's debt ! How immoral is that !!
ordinaryman (not verified) wrote,
Thu, 25/08/2011 - 21:26
The article is well-researched, clear and accurate in its arguments. However, I should like to emphasise the mean and underhanded way in which the Coalition Government has introduced this measure without any consultation and against almost 40 years of precedent. To begin with it financially penalises pensioners who have been drawing their pensions for many, many years in the expectation, based on published information from schemes that these would be uprated each year according to the RPI. Such a retrospective move to punish those who have given a lifetime of service is bordering on the criminal and is breathtaking in its cynicism.
Even worse is the fact that the Government call the CPI ' the Bank of England's 'preferred measure of inflation' yet the Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee members are paid pensions according to the RPI as are Members of Parliament. And, we are supposedly 'all in this together'.
The legal challenge to this Government measure by means of a Judicial Review to be heard this October needs to be successful or we are all going to continue to be massively poorer as a consequence of this abominable action. If unsuccessful, it should be pursued right up to the European Court of Human Rights.
Pensioners, present and future are a considerable electoral force who are unlikely to forget a betrayal.
Anonymous (not verified) wrote,
Sat, 27/08/2011 - 17:51
I have been following the various RPI V's CPI debates closely - and fully agree that the pensioner (least of all able) is being robbed blind by this government's underhanded tactics.
Moreover, whilst most companies acted as quickly as possible in converting from RPI to CPI, the government (who instigated this robbery) and it's MP's are slow to adopt their own medicine ie: they are NOT converting to the LOWER CPI rating till 2012 / 2013. Fancy that..........
I just hope there is a head of steam to force this government into another U-turn; something they seem well versed at doing - especially when it clear that their knee jerk policies are about to explode in their faces!
OPA member (not verified) wrote,
Mon, 24/10/2011 - 20:36
Dr Courtney has published another paper here:
http://www.abaponline.org/styled-6/downloads-2/index.html
Essential reading!
David Quinn (not verified) wrote,
Mon, 14/11/2011 - 19:20
Hi Jim and Jill - Good to see support for Jim's petition spreading. I have written inter alia to 6 Gen Secs of public service unions asking them to publicize it. Two replied saying they had done so. No reply from the others. I heard from the PSPC campaign that the NUT is planning to do their own petition. How stupid is that. Playing right into the government's hand by splitting the vote. I think Jim should write to the NUT and complain. If you haven't read this report by Mark Courtenay on the BA pension fund CPI decision it is informative and pretty well proves the point that CPI as an index is deeply flawed to the point of being a scam http://www.abaponline.org/styled-6/downloads-2/files/MC%20CPI%20report.pdf